TutorChase logo
Login
OCR A-Level History Study Notes

54.2.6 Economy after 1975 and Regional Variation

OCR Specification focus:
‘After 1975, reforms diversified the economy with notable regional variations.’

After 1975, China’s economy transformed under Deng Xiaoping’s pragmatic leadership, shifting from rigid central planning to market-oriented reforms, decentralisation, and openness, creating significant regional disparities and sustained growth.

Economic Transformation under Deng Xiaoping

Pragmatism and Policy Shift

Following Mao Zedong’s death in 1976, China’s leadership sought to reverse the economic stagnation and inefficiencies of the late Maoist era. Deng Xiaoping, who emerged as China’s paramount leader by 1978, prioritised economic modernisation over ideological purity. His guiding principle of “socialism with Chinese characteristics” marked a decisive turn from Maoist orthodoxy toward pragmatic policy experimentation and global engagement.

Socialism with Chinese Characteristics: A political and economic approach that retains socialist governance but incorporates market mechanisms and foreign investment to promote development.

This new direction was embodied in the Four Modernisations — agriculture, industry, defence, and science and technology — first proposed by Zhou Enlai in the 1960s and vigorously pursued under Deng. The aim was to modernise China’s economic foundations and reintroduce incentives for productivity and innovation.

Economic Reforms and Structural Change

From Central Planning to Market Orientation

The pre-1978 economy was dominated by central planning, state-owned enterprises (SOEs), and collective agriculture. Deng’s reforms deliberately dismantled many of these structures:

  • Agricultural reform: Beginning in 1978, the Household Responsibility System replaced collective farming, granting families autonomy over land use and allowing them to sell surplus produce on the market.

  • Industrial reform: SOEs were granted greater managerial autonomy and performance incentives, while new township and village enterprises (TVEs) emerged as dynamic forces in rural industrialisation.

  • Price reforms: Dual pricing systems gradually introduced market pricing alongside state quotas, preparing the ground for a full market economy.

  • Foreign trade and investment: Deng encouraged engagement with the global economy through policies of ‘reform and opening up’ (gaige kaifang), shifting China from isolation to integration.

Household Responsibility System: A rural reform policy that allocated land to individual households, allowing them to manage production and sell surplus, thereby increasing agricultural output and income.

These reforms triggered a rapid surge in output and living standards. Agricultural productivity soared, industry diversified, and China’s share of global trade began to expand significantly.

Special Economic Zones and Coastal Development

SEZs as Laboratories for Reform

One of the most transformative policies was the creation of Special Economic Zones (SEZs) in the late 1970s and early 1980s. These zones — including Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Xiamen, and Shantou — were designed to attract foreign direct investment (FDI), promote export-oriented manufacturing, and experiment with market mechanisms without dismantling socialism nationwide.

File:China SEZ Map.png

Map showing China’s Special Economic Zones and open coastal cities designated in the reform era. It locates the early SEZs and the 1984 coastal openings, visually reinforcing the coast-first strategy. Clear labelling supports analysis of regional divergence without extraneous detail. Source

Key features of SEZs:

  • Tax incentives for foreign investors.

  • Relaxed regulations and streamlined bureaucracy.

  • Infrastructure investment and priority access to credit.

  • Freedom to experiment with labour and wage policies.

The success of SEZs transformed previously rural regions into industrial hubs, especially Shenzhen, which evolved from a fishing village into a major metropolis and symbol of China’s reform era.

Regional Variation and Uneven Development

The Coastal-Inland Divide

Economic reforms were not applied uniformly across China. Deng’s policy of “letting some regions get rich first” fostered uneven growth, particularly between coastal and interior provinces.

China – Industry (1983) thematic map indicating major industrial centres and belts on the eve of accelerated reform. It highlights the coastally concentrated pattern of industrial activity, foreshadowing sharper regional disparities through the 1980s. Source

  • Coastal provinces such as Guangdong, Fujian, Zhejiang, and Jiangsu became engines of export-led growth, benefiting from proximity to global markets and the concentration of SEZs.

  • Interior and western provinces, reliant on state planning and resource extraction, lagged behind, experiencing slower industrialisation and less foreign investment.

  • Urban-rural disparities widened, as urban centres grew rapidly while many rural areas remained underdeveloped.

The regional imbalance became a defining feature of China’s post-1975 economic landscape. Coastal cities experienced double-digit growth, while some inland areas struggled to match national averages, leading to migration, income disparities, and social tensions.

Expansion of Foreign Trade and Investment

Integration into the Global Economy

The post-1978 era saw China’s transition from autarky to a major global trading power. The state encouraged joint ventures, technology transfer, and export-oriented industries. Policies to attract FDI were particularly concentrated in coastal areas, intensifying regional inequalities but fuelling rapid growth.

Key developments included:

  • Rapid expansion of export processing zones.

  • Increased foreign participation in manufacturing and infrastructure.

  • Negotiations for entry into the World Trade Organization (WTO), which China eventually joined in 2001 (beyond the period but initiated during the reform era)

By the late 1980s, foreign trade accounted for a significant share of GDP, and China had become deeply integrated into global supply chains.

State Role and the Socialist Market Economy

Balancing Planning and Market Forces

While reforms embraced market mechanisms, the state retained a crucial role in guiding development. The concept of a socialist market economy, first officially endorsed in 1992, encapsulated this balance.

  • Five-Year Plans continued to set strategic priorities, particularly in heavy industry, energy, and defence.

  • The state maintained control over “commanding heights” of the economy, including banking, telecommunications, and transport.

  • Market forces were allowed to allocate resources in non-strategic sectors, spurring competition and innovation.

Socialist Market Economy: An economic system that combines state ownership and central planning in key sectors with market forces guiding resource allocation in other areas.

This hybrid model proved effective in sustaining high growth rates while maintaining political control.

Socioeconomic Consequences of Reform

Growth, Disparity, and Transformation

The economic changes after 1975 had profound social and regional effects:

  • Rapid economic growth: China’s GDP grew at an average annual rate of around 9–10% during the 1980s and 1990s.

  • Rising living standards: Millions were lifted out of poverty, and consumer goods became widely available.

  • Urbanisation: Massive migration from rural to urban areas reshaped China’s demographic and economic landscape.

  • Regional inequality: Economic divergence deepened, leading to government initiatives such as the ‘Go West’ policy in the late 1990s to promote inland development.

Despite disparities, the transformation of China’s economy after 1975 laid the foundation for its emergence as a global economic superpower in the decades that followed. Deng’s emphasis on pragmatism and openness reshaped the country’s trajectory, embedding regional variation as both a challenge and a driver of continued reform.

FAQ

FDI was central to China’s post-1975 growth strategy. The government offered tax breaks, simplified bureaucracy, and legal protections to attract foreign companies, particularly into Special Economic Zones (SEZs).

Foreign capital brought modern technology, management expertise, and export networks, which accelerated industrialisation and integration into global supply chains.

By the late 1980s, joint ventures and wholly foreign-owned enterprises accounted for a significant share of China’s manufacturing output and exports, reinforcing coastal regions as growth engines.

TVEs were collectively or privately run businesses in rural areas that emerged during the reform era. They absorbed surplus agricultural labour and diversified local economies beyond farming.

Their flexibility allowed them to respond quickly to market demand, producing goods ranging from textiles to machinery.

TVEs played a crucial role in reducing rural poverty, raising incomes, and narrowing the urban-rural gap in the early reform period, even as regional disparities persisted overall.

Deng feared that abrupt liberalisation could destabilise China’s political system and economy. Gradual reform allowed experimentation on a limited scale — such as testing policies in SEZs — before nationwide implementation.

This step-by-step strategy reduced the risk of major policy failures and helped overcome resistance from conservative elements within the Communist Party.

It also allowed state institutions and enterprises to adapt slowly to market mechanisms, preserving political control while pursuing economic modernisation.

Rapid growth in coastal provinces created millions of new jobs in factories, construction, and services, attracting rural workers from inland regions.

This led to one of the largest internal migrations in history, with hundreds of millions of people moving to urban and coastal areas.

While this migration boosted productivity and urban development, it also created social challenges, such as overcrowded cities, strained public services, and unequal access to education and healthcare for migrant families.

Recognising the widening coastal-inland divide, the government launched initiatives to stimulate growth in underdeveloped regions.

  • The “Go West” policy (from 1999) encouraged investment in western provinces through infrastructure projects, tax incentives, and development funds.

  • Regional development zones and targeted poverty alleviation programmes sought to modernise industry and improve living standards inland.

While these policies narrowed some gaps, coastal regions continued to dominate China’s economic output due to their entrenched advantages in trade and investment.

Practice Questions

Question 1 (2 marks)
Identify two Special Economic Zones (SEZs) established during China’s economic reforms after 1978.


Mark Scheme:

  • 1 mark for each correctly identified SEZ (maximum 2 marks).
    Accept any two of the following:

  • Shenzhen

  • Zhuhai

  • Xiamen

  • Shantou

Question 2 (6 marks)
Explain how economic reforms after 1975 contributed to regional variation in China’s development.

Mark Scheme:
Level 1 (1–2 marks): Basic statements with limited detail.

  • Mentions reforms but provides little explanation (e.g., “Some regions grew faster than others.”).

  • May identify coastal areas growing faster but without linking to policy.

Level 2 (3–4 marks): Some explanation with relevant examples.

  • Explains that reforms such as SEZs and foreign investment policies targeted coastal provinces first.

  • Recognises that these policies caused faster growth in eastern regions compared to the interior.

Level 3 (5–6 marks): Detailed and well-supported explanation.

  • Clearly explains how policies like the establishment of SEZs and the “letting some regions get rich first” approach led to uneven development.

  • Uses examples such as rapid growth in Guangdong and Fujian versus slower progress inland.

  • May mention consequences like urban-rural migration or government responses to disparities.

Hire a tutor

Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

1/2
Your details
Alternatively contact us via
WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email